Эротические рассказы

India. Craig JeffreyЧитать онлайн книгу.

India - Craig Jeffrey


Скачать книгу
unmistakable inflection point in the journey of the Republic … The outcome must be understood as an electoral endorsement of Hindutva, or Hindu nationalism’. Whereas the mainstream of Indian political life and culture was committed to liberal values, it has now been taken over by majoritarian Hindu nationalism. Liberal democracy is in retreat.

      Wilson’s conclusions can certainly be disputed, and there are other historians who emphasize positive aspects of colonial rule. The economic historian Tirthanka Roy, for example, though he is not an apologist for empire, thinks that openness and integration into the world economy in the nineteenth century helped Indian business to overcome constraints to which it was subject: ‘By bringing in knowledge and capital from Britain to India, the open economy enabled huge growth in trade and an off-beat industrialization in the 19th century’ (Roy 2018: 261). Roy is critical of the long-established argument that the British effectively ‘underdeveloped’ India, through the open economy that they encouraged. This was the thesis of Indian economic nationalists in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries (whose arguments actually influenced the formulation of the idea of ‘underdevelopment’ by its foremost exponent, A. G. Frank, in the 1960s–70s – see Frank 1967). They emphasized the ‘drain’ of wealth from India to Britain, through onerous taxation, especially of agriculture, that both paid for the purchase of Indian goods that could then be sold by the colonizers at considerable profit, and for the ‘home charges’ – payments to Britain for the government of India and for the maintenance of the Indian army (which was deployed to extend and to police other parts of the British empire). Some historians have emphasized, too, both the impoverishment of Indian cultivators by the high levels of tax that they paid on the land (land revenue payments), and the ‘deindustrialization’ of India by the British, in the interests especially of the British cotton mill industry (and resistance to the purchase of British-made cotton textiles was one of the rallying cries of the struggle for independence from colonial rule). Roy, however, argues that the long-standing focus of scholars of world history on why India fell behind has led them to miss the central paradox of Indian economic history, which he thinks was the coexistence of robust capitalism and stagnant agriculture.

      Debate will continue about the economic impact of colonialism in India. There is no room for doubt, however, about India’s declining share in the global economy in the nineteenth century, and the increasing divergence between India and other countries in Asia and the West. At the same time, as Roy argues, there was a successful Indian capitalist class, and successful Indian-owned industries – cotton mills in Bombay (now Mumbai), for example, and the first steelworks established in Asia, set up in eastern India by the Parsi entrepreneur Jamsetji Tata, founder of the company that now owns such an important share of British manufacturing industry. Roy’s argument, too, about ‘stagnant agriculture’ in colonial India is incontrovertible. Evidence collected by Myrdal for his classic work, Asian Drama (1968), shows how poor agricultural productivity was in India, by comparison with much of the rest of Asia, around the time of independence in 1947. Independent India faced a very significant ‘agrarian question’ – what to do about the productivity of agriculture and the poverty of the mass of the people who continued to live in the villages.

      But though there was industrialization in colonial India, the great majority of the population and of the labour force remained in the villages and in agriculture. How far, therefore, can there have been the ‘social revolution’ in India that Marx anticipated in the middle of the nineteenth century? He thought that the ‘village system’ of India was being dissolved as a result of ‘English interference’, and that colonialism was producing ‘the greatest, and to speak the truth, the only social revolution ever heard of in Asia’ (Marx 1853). Marx argued that the development of roads and railways by the British rulers would break down the isolation of India’s villages, and that with new irrigation systems and the development of industry, a ‘social revolution’ would come about. More recently, however, historians have often found reason for arguing that there was considerable continuity, as well as change. The British very largely took over, though they also developed, earlier systems for the taxation of land (discussed by Banerjee and Iyer, whose work is referred to above), and this ensured the reproduction of the power of small numbers of landlords over the very large numbers of small cultivators, under a variety of systems that often made for insecurity of tenure for the actual cultivators of the land. Those with more secure rights, however, and those who held larger amounts of land, became politically powerful in the later part of the colonial period, effectively


Скачать книгу
Яндекс.Метрика