Эротические рассказы

The Handbook of Peer Production. Группа авторовЧитать онлайн книгу.

The Handbook of Peer Production - Группа авторов


Скачать книгу
a restricted leadership are situated in quadrant A. In contrast to employees of capitalist‐centralized firms, independent workers such as informal networks of tradespeople in quadrant C have much greater latitude as to whether to work on a particular job. Quadrants B and D comprise communal forms of labor. The community validation and self‐fulfillment of domestic labor are lesser than those accrued by participants in voluntary/collectivist associations, but they exist nonetheless. Indeed, Marxist feminist scholar Kylie Jarrett (2016) draws a comparison between the affective or reproductive work of traditional housewives and the unpaid labor performed by contributors to digital platforms. But where workers in quadrant D have control over their production, workers in quadrant B who freely engage in consumption work (or its more interactive variants “prosumption” and “co‐creation”) must accept that their contributions to product development or networked communication are subject to an external authority's approval or disapproval, with no possibility of redress: this distinction is perhaps not sufficiently drawn out in Jarrett’s (2016) otherwise excellent book, which conflates FOSS labor with that of Facebook users for example.

      Source: O’Neil, M. (2015). Labour out of control. The political economy of capitalist and ethical organizations. Organization Studies, 36(12): 1627–1647. © 2015 SAGE Publications.

Capitalist logic (“alienated” labor) Ethical logic (“communal” labor)
Centralized governance A private firms, public administration, non‐governmental organizations B consumption work, co‐creation, prosumption
Modular governance C independent workers, freelancers, contractors D domestic labor, voluntary/collectivist organizations

      4.3 How Capitalism Co‐opts Peer Production: The Case of Free and Open Source Software

      Early critical understandings of Californian Internet culture (Barbrook & Cameron, 1996), of online communities (Terranova, 2000), and of computer hacking (Wark, 2004) took it for granted that capitalist interests would seek to capture autonomous online labor, though these accounts were in the main written when this co‐optation was an interesting novelty, rather than a central component of IT firms’ business model, as it is today. But how did the integration of communities of peer producers into the “ecosystems” of firms come about?

      Boltanski and Chiapello (2005) had presciently argued in their book on the “new spirit of capitalism,” originally published in 1999, that capitalism uses critique to rejuvenate itself, by integrating the 1960s countercultural critique of tradition, boredom, and hierarchy. This helped to justify the freeing of capital, the deployment of anti‐welfarist ideology, the weakening of the state and the erosion of organized labor by emphasizing personal liberation rather than social emancipation, which alleviates exploitation. To these insights Fisher (2010) added the legitimizing function of a technological discourse in which hackers are a central productive force. Similarly for Barron (2013), FOSS exemplifies a particularly pure form of the “new spirit of capitalism”: a post‐Fordist regime of accumulation, arranged around lean firms working as networks with a multitude of participants, organizing work in the form of teams or projects, intent on customer satisfaction, and a general mobilization of workers thanks to their leaders’ vision.

      In an article detailing how hacker practices and innovations are adopted, adapted, and repurposed by corporate and political actors, Delfanti and Söderberg (2018) reprise the notion that assimilated critiques serve to legitimize capitalism and suggest that hacking itself is being hacked, as “the very idea that tinkering offers a way to subvert the agendas of the powers‐that‐be has become a foundational myth of contemporary capitalism” (p. 461). Beyond repurposing, technical innovations such as modularized production and distributed mesh networks and retrieval systems are now “integrated in the material infrastructure of capitalism” (p. 476), and coupled with distrust for incumbent actors, aka “disruption.”

      Christopher Kelty’s (2008) influential definition of FOSS projects as “recursive” is key to understanding how what was once perceived as a force resisting privatization has been integrated into dominant circuits of capital. Hackers have extremely divergent politics, but they all agree that proprietary software and intellectual property rights, as well as surveillance and censorship, should be rejected. This stems from the fact that such an opposition constitutes the techno‐legal preconditions for the hacker public to exist as such: “recursive politics” aim to consolidate and grow the material conditions for the survival of this public. In contrast issues such as feminism and workers’ rights are not “recursive” in the sense that hackers “perceive them to be unrelated to what really matters to them the most, computers and Internet freedom” (Delfanti & Söderberg, 2018, p. 463). This was the key for the disruptive potential of FOSS to be tamed: all firms needed to do was to adopt hackers’ core demand (providing access to code through “open” licenses) to ensure that participants could continue to help their environments thrive. The ethical logic of self‐fulfillment and the focus on technical excellence did the rest, imbuing projects with a propensity to accept any valid contribution (irrespective of whether it originates from a commercial or communal setting) and an aversion to discussing questions of subsistence (“who can afford to take part?”), as such discussions complicate the notion that contributions are solely evaluated on merit.

      Lund and Zukerfeld (2020) suggest that profit deriving from what they call the “enclosures model” seeks to increase the price of outputs, whilst profit deriving from the “openness model” seeks to decrease as much as possible the price of inputs. Copyright‐based production processes exploit productive activities during labor time, whilst “profit from openness is to a greater extent based on the exploitation of productive activities during leisure time” (Lund & Zukerfeld, 2020, p. 23). For these authors, firm adoption of FOSS is part of an emerging “Openness Ideology” representing a shift from a “profit from enclosures” model (based on the rhetoric of individuals, property, and exclusion) to a “profit from openness” model which extols the virtues of communities, inclusion, and freedom: the peer production of software opened the way for the wholesale capture


Скачать книгу
Яндекс.Метрика