Эротические рассказы

The Handbook of Peer Production. Группа авторовЧитать онлайн книгу.

The Handbook of Peer Production - Группа авторов


Скачать книгу
the available surplus of computing resources. Reciprocity‐based schemes are necessary in the material sphere where the higher cost of capital intervenes. At present, peer production offers no coherent solution to the material survival of its participants, though as we discuss below, there are some promising solutions to such challenges. Therefore, many people inspired by the egalitarian ethos will resort to cooperative production, the social economy, and other schemes from which they can derive an income, while honoring their values. In this sense, these schemes are complementary. The open cooperative and the platform cooperative movements, however, showcase how peer producers may make a sustainable living (Bauwens et al., 2019; Scholz & Schneider, 2016).

      3.3 Equipotentiality

      Michel Bauwens (2005) suggested that P2P processes aim to increase the most widespread participation by equipotential (“equal” + “potential”) participants. The processes of peer production are characterized by the adoption of equipotentiality as an organizing principle. This means that everyone can potentially cooperate in a project, and, thus, in principle no authority can pre‐judge the ability to cooperate. The quality of cooperation is then judged by the community of peers, i.e., through communal validation. In equipotential projects, participants self‐sort themselves into the module to which they feel able to contribute.

      A related term, used by Jimmy Wales (2014) of the Wikipedia project, is anti‐credentialism, which refers to the fact that no credentials are asked beforehand. This means that there is no a priori selection to participation. What matters is the ability to carry out a particular task, not any formal a priori credential. The capacity to cooperate is verified in the process of cooperation itself. Thus, projects are often open to all comers provided they have the necessary skills to contribute to a project. These skills are verified, and communally validated, in the process of production itself. Reputation systems may also be used for communal validation. The filtering is a posteriori, not a priori. Anti‐credentialism is therefore to be contrasted to traditional peer review, where credentials are an essential prerequisite to participate. However, the “expert” is not a persona non grata in peer production (O’Neil, 2010). Rather, equipotentiality, through a process that is far from flawless, allows the crowds to engage with experts to produce content, designs, code, and more.

      3.4 Holoptism

      Another element of the grammar of peer production is that projects are characterized by holoptism, as opposed to panopticism (Foucault, 1977) in which only a centralized power can see the whole. Holoptism, from the Greek o&c.rcomab;λος (“whole”) and o&c.comabr;πτικος (“seeing”), is the implied capacity and design of peer production processes that allows participants free access to all the information about the other participants; not in terms of privacy, but in terms of their existence and contributions (i.e., horizontal information) and access to the aims, metrics, and documentation of the project as a whole (i.e., the vertical dimension). This can be contrasted to the panopticism that is characteristic of traditionally hierarchical projects: processes are designed to reserve “total” knowledge for an elite, while participants only have access on a “need to know” basis. In peer production, communication is not top‐down and based on strictly defined reporting rules, but feedback is systemic and integrated in the protocol of the cooperative system.

      3.5 Stigmergic Cooperation

      In peer production some producers may be paid or employed as wage labor, or work for the market as freelancers, but not necessarily. All of them produce a commons. The work is not directed by the corporate hierarchies, but through the mutual coordination mechanisms of the productive community, to which the corporate hierarchies have to defer if they want to participate in this type of production. Peer production is based on open and transparent systems, in which everyone can see the signals of the work done by others, and can, therefore, adapt their contribution to the needs of the system as a whole.

      3.6 Modularity, Granularity, and Low‐Cost of Integration

      Other authors have of course made significant contributions to the grammar of peer production. For example, stigmergic collaboration is enabled by three characteristics, identified by Benkler (2006) as embedded in the social design of a peer production project: modularity, granularity, and low cost of integration. To begin with, the project needs to be broken down into smaller components, i.e., into modules. For example, in Wikipedia the content is divided into entries, sections, and paragraphs. People can contribute from one word to thousands of words (or figures). The modules allow for any size of contribution: there are many levels of granularity to match different levels of contributors’ motivation and time availability.

      So, tasks, products and services are organized as modules, which fit with other modules in a puzzle that is continuously re‐assembled. And granularity is a property of creating the smallest possible modules with the aim of lowering the threshold of participation (Benkler, 2006). Further, it should be easy to put the various contributions (the modules) into the final product. Also, effective quality‐control mechanisms should be in place to avoid low quality of contributions.

      3.7 Heterarchy

      That being said, peer production projects do have systems of quality control. These “maintainers” (in free and open source software) or “editors” (in Wikipedia) protect the integrity of the system as a whole and can refuse contributions that endanger the integrity of the system. However, they do not coerce work. Peer production is based on freely engaged and passionate labor. Moreover, it eliminates some costs to capital. Hence, as we discuss next, it can also be embraced by for‐profit‐maximization forces, which explains the massive growth of peer production as a means to produce software for industry.

      Peer production is neither hierarchy‐less, nor structure‐less (Freeman, 1970; Bauwens in Kostakis, 2010), but usually characterized by flexible and dynamic hierarchies and structures based on merit that are used to enable participation. Heterarchies combine elements of networks and hierarchies. Carole Crumley has offered


Скачать книгу
Яндекс.Метрика